Introduction
[This is posted on http://desgriffin.com/2016/12/jobs-and-growth-the-great-tax-hoax/.]
The
Coalition government in Australia and the policy of the incoming President of
the US Donald Trump propose substantial decreases in corporate tax rates and
assert this will stimulate growth and jobs.
However,
consideration of past decreases in tax rates reveals the recent behaviour of
corporations and their executives and boards as an increasing trend to devote
retained earnings to share buy backs and dividend distribution. Thus additional
revenue flowing from further tax breaks is likely to contribute to further enrichment
of the already super rich including many at the helm of large corporations,
especially in the financial sector. Few companies are paying the marginal tax
rate and many are avoiding tax altogether.
The
campaigns by business to downsize government, reduce wage growth, limit union
influence and reduce regulation have been self-defeating. The behaviour of the
super-rich is the principal driver of the significant increase in inequality
over the last 40 or so years, especially the Global Financial Crisis. This has
led to a stalling of demand. In Australia, substantial investment has been
directed to property, now a vehicle for financial enrichment at the expense of
those wishing to find somewhere to live.
It
is vitally important to recall that rising prosperity benefiting the population
generally does not depend simply on economic growth: unending growth is a
concept believed in only by the naive and many economists. The United Nations Development
Program Report for 2009, Real Wealth of
Nations: Pathways to Human Development points out that improvements around
the world in education and health have been due principally to cross border
transfer of ideas: there is little if any correlation with economic growth! Growth
in incomes is not unimportant but it is not the main reason for improved
prosperity.
In
other words we can learn a great deal from other countries and other domains:
seeking out those lessons is vitally important. Most particularly the notion
that for any individual country the growth of population is critical is
nonsense. Indeed, countries where the birth rate has slowed are generally more
prosperous and a significant influence on that is education of women.
Governments
have a fundamentally critical role in both encouraging transfer of ideas, in
the provision of education for women and in encouraging responsible and
sustainable population policy. Many developed economies lack any coherent
population policy.
In
Australia weakening of institutions, increasing inequality, primitive
approaches to debt, especially for infrastructure development and to deficit
budgeting, ongoing downsizing of government along with poor investment in
education, health and science and a lack of understanding of innovation and
what drives it is putting Australia’s future at risk. Isolation from the ideas
emerging in other countries is a major feature of public policy!
Related
post:
A
postscript to the associated essay [below] “Managerial Firms and Rentiers” notes the
recently published book on Neoliberalism by George Monbiot and also deals with the behaviour of banks
and the involvement of US administration officials in failing to prosecute bank
executives for their behaviour which led to the Global Financial Crisis.
______
Managerial Firms and Rentiers: How Corporate
Behaviour is driving Inequality
One
of the main elements of the Federal Government’s economic “plan” is to reduce
taxes on corporations. In the Midyear Economic Forecast (MYEFO) delivered
mid-December 2016 Treasurer Scott Morrison argued again for the
corporate tax rate to be cut to 25 per cent – from the present 30 per
cent - saying more needs to be done to encourage businesses to invest and
employ more Australians, in order to stimulate economic growth.
Though
the Coalition argues that the change would boost GDP by more than 1 per cent in
the long-term, the net benefit, according to Grattan
Institute economists,
would more likely be half that and not appear for many years. The measure,
which would cost an estimated $50 billion over 10 years, needs the approval of
the Senate where it likely will be blocked.
Labor
Opposition Treasury spokesman Chris Bowen, pointing to the long lead time and
small impact, has repeatedly opposed the Coalition plan: the ALP advocates a
tax cut for companies earning no more than $50 million. (Senator Nick Xenophon
favours tax reductions for firms earning up to $10 millions.)
Donald
Trump, President-elect of the United States, has also promised to reduce
corporate taxes. The proposals include cutting the
corporate tax rate from thirty-five per cent to fifteen per cent and allowing
firms to pay a rate of just ten per cent if they repatriate profits. On Forbes,
recent commentary pointed
out,
“First, tax cuts would have to be enormous to have any macroeconomic effect on
a $16-18 trillion economy… Second, even if enhanced growth were achieved, it
would not be evenly distributed. US income taxes are progressive. Spending is
not, so the system as a whole is not redistributive. And as the individual discussion
shows, it would not put a lot more money in the hands of people with a high
marginal propensity to consume.”
In
December Prime Minister Turnbull expressed the hope that the decision by
President-elect Trump to press ahead with corporate tax cuts would strengthen
governments’ hand in achieving the proposed cuts in Australia.
This essay advances the proposition, based on significant economic literature, that tax cuts will not achieve the purposes which are promoted because of tax minimisation and profit alienation or even non-existent. A significant number of large companies are in fact using retained earnings to buy back shares and increase dividends so restricting funds for growth and diversification. Thus the fundamental driver of increased economic activity, increased demand, is not there, very much because ordinary wages have been held back.
This essay advances the proposition, based on significant economic literature, that tax cuts will not achieve the purposes which are promoted because of tax minimisation and profit alienation or even non-existent. A significant number of large companies are in fact using retained earnings to buy back shares and increase dividends so restricting funds for growth and diversification. Thus the fundamental driver of increased economic activity, increased demand, is not there, very much because ordinary wages have been held back.
The
increase in profits flowing from tax breaks to major corporations might give
another boost to the stock market but the money won’t be spent on capital
spending and growth. It will be spent on share repurchases. It is a consequence
of the relatively recent view that the principal purpose of the corporation is
to increase the wealth of shareholders.
The
proposition that corporate tax cuts will not end up stimulating the economy is
not based on economic theory but on experience. High corporate taxes are not
holding back investment, short-term strategies and weak demand are.
The
weak demand is a consequence of polices adopted by government at the behest of
corporations to keep a cap on wages growth. The top one percent of earners take
home more than 20 percent of the income, and their share has more than doubled
in the last thirty-five years, as so many including Nobel Prizewinner Joseph
Stiglitz, have pointed out. The gains for people in the top 0.1 percent,
meanwhile, have been even greater. Yet over that same period, average wages and
household incomes in the US have risen only slightly, and a number of
demographic groups (like men with only a high school education) have actually
seen their average wages decline.
Productive
Achievement and Tax Cuts for Business
In
an incisive article on The New Yorker
for 22 December 2016, long-time staff writer John Cassidy observes, “One reason
the U.S. economy has grown relatively slowly over the past eight years is that
corporations have been sitting on their cash rather than investing it in things
like factories, offices, and new equipment—a failure widely attributed to depressed
animal spirits.
“It
is the sort of Randian analysis [a reference to Russian-American novelist and
philosopher Ayn Rand who considered productive achievement the noblest activity
of man] long favored by many people on Wall Street, and recently promoted by
some of Trump’s closest economic advisers: if you want capitalism to work more
effectively, offer greater rewards to the capitalists. Cut taxes, rein in
regulation, and create an environment that incentivizes financial risk-taking.
The free market … will do the rest.” Indeed the view is that Trump’s proposals would
generate “a tremendous movement, of
capital and labor back to the United States, that’s in China and overseas.”
Cassidy
quotes Ray Dalio, the founder and chief executive of American Investment
Management firm Bridgewater Associates, “This new administration hates weak,
unproductive, socialist people and policies, and it admires strong, can-do,
profit makers. It wants to, and probably will, shift the environment from one
that makes profit makers villains with limited power to one that makes them
heroes with significant power.”
“Dalio
claimed that the Trump era could be even more significant than the 1978-1982
shift to the right that saw Margaret Thatcher, Ronald Reagan, and Helmut Kohl elected—one
of the big questions is whether the new policies being implemented will work.
Dalio offered an upbeat prognosis. He argued that Trump’s proposals to slash
corporate tax rates and give big businesses like Apple and Microsoft financial
incentives to repatriate trillions of dollars in profits that they are holding
abroad could “ignite animal spirits and attract productive capital” to the
United States.”
Inequality,
Shareholder Wealth and Corporate Power
Columbia
University economist Jeffrey Sachs, in his 2012 book The Price of Civilisation reviewed by Ross
Gittins,
says the US economy is caught in a feedback loop: “'Corporate wealth translates
into political power through campaign financing, corporate lobbying and the
revolving door of jobs between government and industry; and political power
translates into further wealth through tax cuts, deregulation and sweetheart
contracts between government and industry. Wealth begets power, and power
begets wealth.'' The military-industrial, Wall Street-Washington and Big
Oil-transport-military complexes and the healthcare industry all play their
part.
Gittins’
more recent commentary on bad behaviour of
business, stemming from current economic orthodoxy and
its obsession with demanding measures of performance – Key Performance
Indicators (KPIs) - without any concern for methods or process, is just one of
many criticisms. The faddish translation of imagined business practice to
government agencies has led to the latter adopting KPIs as a central part of
forward planning as if they are the core of strategy, which they are not!
A
series of research papers and articles elucidate these issues. Governments have
ignored the behaviour of corporations and failed to address the consequences of
continual cutbacks in government and slow wages growth.
Professor
J. B. Foster of the University of Oregon & M. D. Yates, both researchers on
inequality, in a review ‘Piketty and the
Crisis of Neoclassical Economics (Monthly
Review October 2014) quote a recent paper by Economic Policy Institute
economist Elise Gould which points out that between 1979 and 2013, productivity
grew 64.9 percent, while hourly compensation of production and nonsupervisory workers,
who comprise over 80 percent of the private-sector workforce, grew just 8.0
percent. Productivity thus grew eight times faster than typical worker
compensation. Further, over roughly the same period, income and wealth levels,
rather than converging, have diverged sharply—a divergence that cannot be
attributed to differences in education and skill, nor to the contributions of
capital relative to labor (as shown by Lawrence Mishel, “Education
is Not the Cure for High Unemployment or for Income Inequality,” January 12, 2011
also quoted by Foster & Yates).
Ian
McAuley, Centre for Policy Development Fellow, in a New Matilda article in August 2014, referred to the Australian economy as
a Ponzi Scheme,
one in which current income is diverted to paying earlier investors and not to new
investment. He notes “As the profit reporting season runs its course, it is
becoming clear that many companies have chosen to pay out high dividends, while
keeping aside a smaller proportion of profits for re-investment. Of course it
is quite legal for firms to pay high dividends and to make capital returns, but
in many ways the results resemble those of Ponzi schemes. Higher dividends,
higher share prices, and capital returns all favour corporate managers, who
receive much of their pay in stocks or stock options. It’s not dissimilar to the
early stages of a Ponzi scheme, where both the promoters and the investors do
well.”
McAuley
quotes the statement by then Reserve Bank Governor Glenn Stevens: “if reports
are to believed, many businesses remain intent on sustaining a flow of
dividends and returning capital to shareholders and are somewhat less focussed
on implementing plans for growth”. Stevens was appearing before the House of
Representatives Standing Committee on Economics. Giant telecommunications
company Telstra was just one of the companies embarking on share buyback to
inflate dividends.
Corporate Investment
and Executive Risk: No Downside
In a review of changes in corporate
investment strategy over the last four decades, J W Mason in ‘Disgorge the Cash’ (Roosevelt
Institute, February 25, 2015) distinguishes the managerial firm as one in which
managers make the major decisions on investment and stockholders are passive
recipients of dividends and the rentier firm as one in which the stockholder
are active and pursue management to increase the stock price and return higher
dividends and the proceeds of stock buybacks. The thesis tested by Mason in his
survey of the history of corporate governance is that up to the late 70s most
firms were managerial ones but increasingly since the 1980s more and more firms
have become rentiers.
Mason says, “the strong empirical
relationship of corporate cash flow and borrowing to productive corporate
investment has disappeared in the last 30 years and has been replaced with
corporate funds and shareholder payouts. Whereas firms once borrowed to invest
and improve their long-term performance, they now borrow to enrich their
investors in the short-run. This is the result of legal, managerial, and
structural changes that resulted from the shareholder revolution of the 1980s.
Under the older, managerial, model, more money coming into a firm – from sales
or from borrowing – typically meant more money spent on fixed investment. In
the new rentier-dominated model, more money coming in means more money flowing
out to shareholders in the form of dividends and stock buybacks.
“These
results have important implications for macroeconomic policy. The shareholder
revolution – and its implications for corporate financing decisions – may help
explain why higher corporate profits in recent business cycles have generally
failed to lead to high levels of investment. And under this new system, cheaper
money from lower interest rates will fail to stimulate investment, growth, and
wages because [as he shows] additional funds are funneled to shareholders
through buybacks and dividends.”
Professor William
Lazonick (University of Massachusetts’ Centre for Effective Public Management)
in “Stock buybacks: From retain-and-reinvest to downsize-and-distribute” (April
2015) observed, “Over the decade 2004-2013, 454 companies in S&P 500 Index in March
2014 that were publicly listed over the ten years did $3.4 trillion in stock
buybacks, representing 51 percent of net income. These companies expended an
additional 35 percent of net income on dividends.5 And buybacks remain in
vogue: According to data compiled by Factset, for the 12-month period ending
December 2014, S&P 500 companies spent $565 billion on buybacks, up 18
percent from the previous 12-month period.”
Lazonick continues, “Under retain-and-reinvest, the corporation
retains earnings and reinvests them in the productive capabilities embodied in
its labor force. Under downsizeand- distribute, the corporation lays off
experienced, and often more expensive, workers, and distributes corporate cash
to shareholders.”
The pharmaceutical
industry is renowned for charging high prices for its products and claiming
that the prices reflect the high cost of research and development. However,
many drugs developed by companies benefit from basic research conducted by or
with funds from government. Lazonick, in Profits
Without Prosperity (Harvard Business Review September 2014) says,
“In response to complaints that U.S. drug prices are at least twice those in
any other country, Pfizer and other U.S. pharmaceutical companies have argued
that the profits from these high prices—enabled by a generous
intellectual-property regime and lax price regulation—permit more R&D to be
done in the United States than elsewhere. Yet from 2003 through 2012, Pfizer
funneled an amount equal to 71% of its profits into buybacks, and an amount
equal to 75% of its profits into dividends. In other words, it spent more on
buybacks and dividends than it earned and tapped its capital reserves to help
fund them. The reality is, Americans pay high drug prices so that major
pharmaceutical companies can boost their stock prices and pad executive pay.”
In “Economic Hegemony and the
Federal Reserve” (Counterpunch Feb 27–Mar 01) Rob Urie observes, “Theory has it that ownership stakes give executives vested
interest in corporate well-being. By using company earnings or borrowed money
to buy-back stock executives raise the stock price and with it, their own
compensation. This comes at the expense of future production and a potentially
destabilizing increase in leverage. The combined effect is a rigged stock
market and a corporate class that is gutting the broad economy for its own
self-enrichment.”
This
behaviour is occurring also in Australia. Thus, in an article taken from Australian Economy, March 6, 2015 on the
Macrobusiness website under the heading ‘Corporate greed is
killing investment’
addresses the statement, “We all know that the RBA [Reserve Bank of Australia] has
been pushing a line for years that the missing link in the Australian recovery
is business investment owing to poor “confidence”.” The ‘Disgorge the Cash’
paper by Mason, referenced above, is quoted.
The
article continues, “We are not immune. Recall this classic quote from Rodney
Adler when interviewed by David James at BRW [Business Review Weekly] after the
GFC:
“There
has been a major change in the upper middle-management layer of most
corporations. In the old days, which certainly I believe in, the standard
organisation was that equity went into a company, and if you owned that equity
after 20 years’ hard work you made a lot of money if you were successful. About
10 or 20 years ago this all changed. All of a sudden these people on good
salaries who hadn’t taken the risk, who hadn’t built the corporation, they said
to themselves: ‘I’d like to be rich. I’d like to have equity in the company but
I don’t want to buy it.’ And a whole new set of instruments evolved out of
America, which then infested the rest of the world, certainly the Western
world, where executives became owners but with no risk. “[At that point]
capitalism as we know it changed. It is not capitalism because the risk has
gone. The executives have the upside and no down-side. That is the problem.”
The
article concludes, “What does it mean when Rodney Adler makes more sense than
the Reserve Bank.” In other words, it is not lack of confidence that is holding
back investment but the behaviour of corporate executives and other
shareholders in using companies as nothing more than a way to make money
without any contribution to productivity!
In
Kick the dividend
addiction
(ABC The Drum 28 August 2014) distinguished economic journalist Alan Kohler
wrote, “the nation's investors have become obsessed with harvesting dividends
and the companies with supplying them. The share market has become a giant
retiree ATM instead of a means of supplying capital for business investment.
All of the return from the market since the beginning of 2007 - 35.1 per cent -
has come from dividends.”
In ‘Australia’s addiction to
dividends is killing us”, (Business Spectator 4 August 2014) Kohler focused on dividend imputation and the decline in
non-mining capital stock since 1987. “Dividend imputation lowered the cost of
equity for Australian companies and resulted in a structural decline in
gearing, but it has also resulted in sustained pressure on companies to
increase their dividend payout ratios and not retain earnings. The result is
chronic under-investment by companies outside the mining industry, and
especially in manufacturing.”
Where has Tax Revenue
gone?
There
has been a great deal of attention to the taxes actually paid by corporations
in recent months especially. Cassidy notes that the complex tax code in the US,
riddled as it is with loopholes, means that companies don’t pay anything like
the 35 per cent intended. Between 2008 and 2012 it was on average about 14 per
cent, from 2006 to 2012 two thirds of incorporated businesses didn’t pay
anything.
The
situation in Australia is similar, as has been revealed recently. Many large
multinational companies are avoiding tax through profit alienation: among those
companies are the well-known ones such as Amazon, Apple, Samsung, Google and
Microsoft and pharmaceutical companies like Proctor & Gamble and Pfizer.
Some 30 per cent of large private companies pay no tax. Then there are the
astonishing avoidance of tax by the super-rich revealed by the Panama papers. One commentator
asserted,
“the Panama Papers confirm that the super-rich have effectively exited the
economic system the rest of us have to live in. Thirty years of runaway incomes
for those at the top, and the full armoury of expensive financial
sophistication, mean they no longer play by the same rules the rest of us have
to follow. Tax havens are simply one reflection of that reality.”
And
what is the driver of investment anyway? Cassidy notes, “Surveys by the Federal
Reserve Board and other organizations indicate that the main factor depressing
corporate investment has been weak demand. As Keynes pointed out eighty years
ago, when firms don’t see the appetite for their products growing, they have
little incentive to build new capacity. He quotes Dominic Konstam, an analyst
at Deutsche Bank, as saying “the logic is quite simple”. In the absence of
strong (global) final demand there is unlikely to be an increase in investment.
The
low level of demand is a major issue. Corporations in pursuit of neoclassical
economic theory – private sector good, public sector bad - for decades have
urged governments to reduce employment. Further, business has urged governments
and statutory bodies charged with determining wage rates to limit wage rises
and further, to control union demands for wage increases, the basic wage and
remove provisions such as penalty rates for special circumstances.
The
consequence in the US and in Australia and many other developed nations has
been a plateauing or small increment of rates of increase in wages for the
majority of the population. That has meant a decrease in the disposable incomes
of that part of the population most likely to spend generally. The rich are
much more likely to invest their money in various activities such as property
and ones in which financial institutions specialise whereas the bulk of the
population spend disposable income in consumer goods, entertainment, travel and
similar activities.
In
other words, to the extent that economic growth is a function of aggregate
expenditure from disposable income, these campaigns of business and the super-
rich defeat the push for growth. The influence of the super-rich is not to be
discounted. Whilst the divergence has been less in Australia than in the US it
is nevertheless significant. Government policies has particularly targeted
social welfare spending from payments to general practitioners to pensions.
Who is causing the
Great Divergence
In
his analysis of the
“Great Divergence”,
the increase in inequality since the 1980s, Timothy Noah points to the actions
of the super-rich as the principal factor, attributing 30% of the Great
Divergence to their influence. (Noah attributes 30% of the decline to lack of
educational attainment due to rising tuition costs leading to fewer graduates
to meet demand, 20% to the downfall of union’s collective lower wages and 10%
to trade; gender and race, single parenthood and computerisation were
considered by Noah to not have contributed to the rise of inequality and 5%
each to immigration and tax policy.)
And
the growth of the financial sector has been identified as an important factor
contributing to the growth in inequality over the past 30 years. David Rosnick
and Dean Baker of the Center for Economic and Policy Research (CEPR) in
Washington drew this conclusion in a July 2012 report, “Missing the Story The
OECD’s Analysis of Inequality” critical of the OECD’s lengthy volume examining
the causes of rising inequality in most wealthy countries over the last three
decades. They found inequality to be driven by in large part by increasing
income shares at the very top, higher than the 90th percentile;
those earnings come at the expense of those outside the sector so contributing
to their relative decline.
Cassidy
concludes! “The final, and perhaps most important, point to note is that the
Randian theory now being trumpeted was put to the test, not very long ago, and
it failed. In 2004, the Bush Administration introduced a “tax holiday” for
corporations that repatriated profits they were holding abroad, arguing much as
… others are now, that it would spur capital investment and job growth. What
actually happened, according to a Senate subcommittee that surveyed twenty
leading multinational companies, was that “the 2004 repatriation tax provision
was followed by an increase in dollars spent on stock repurchases and executive
compensation.
”Of
course, things could turn out differently this time, but even some analysts at …
Goldman Sachs, doubt that will happen. In a recent research note to clients,
Goldman predicted that three-quarters of the money that big corporations bring
back to the United States next year under the Trump tax plan will end up being
spent on stock buybacks. “We estimate that $150 billion out of $780 billion of
S&P 500 buybacks in 2017 will be driven by repatriated overseas cash,” the
Goldman research note said. “We forecast that S&P 500 companies will
repatriate close to $200 billion of their $1 trillion of total overseas cash in
2017, which will be directed primarily toward share repurchases.”
Then
there were the substantial reductions in corporate tax rates in the 1980s by
both the Reagan and Thatcher administrations in the US and the UK respectively.
Did that generate increased employment and economic activity generally? To what
extent has there been increased activity which can be specifically attributable
to the changes in the tax regime as opposed to other factors? Comparisons of
tax regimes often fail to attend to the complexities in each country, in the
case of the US the fact that there substantial state taxes in addition to
federal taxes and taxes do not include provision for health insurance. And so
on.
Whilst
in Australia, the federal the Coalition government proclaims its concern about
all Australians and the need for more jobs, business continues its rent-seeking,
all the while campaigning for keeping strong control over wages and conditions,
reduction of the budget deficit and cutting government expenditure. The impact of
the resulting inequality is profound and the cost to government tax revenue significant.
In
today’s climate it is also fair to say that curbing excessive corporate
executive pay and increasing employment using the money saved would cost companies
no more and not negatively affect productivity. There is no reason to believe that
paying executives more than a million dollars increases productivity or
innovation. Bonuses for performance are not being paid for superior performance
but merely for average performance.
In
other words the dictum that the board and executive should have as their
primary task the encouragement of above average performance is ignored. The
likelihood of this occurring is of course nil. Firms with a union presence have
lower levels of total executive compensation. Paying lower salaries might well
encourage persons to be engaged who genuinely want to advance the organisation
rather than just enrich themselves.
Treasurer Morrison’s
exhortations just Another Station along the way
The
Government’s campaign on budget repair, the scare campaign on the possibility
of a reduced credit rating by international agencies and the arguments about
unsustainability of social welfare spending based on nonsensical 50 year
projections is all of a piece with the rhetoric of tax cuts for business. These
economic positions are resulting in a continuation of the risk averse approach
to capital expenditure on infrastructure and the argument that future
generations should not be saddled with debt as if failure to invest means that
future generations would face no liability. The fact is that instead of a
financial liability they face unsustainably crowded roads, grossly inadequate
communication systems, poor educational and health infrastructure. All these
are, on the other hand, hardly faced in the day to day experience of the
executives and shareholders in receipt of their dividends. The proposal that
tax cuts will assist economic activity is fraudulent.
Governments
are not working for all the people but for those who have most influence. Treasurer
Morrison’s exhortations are just another station along the way. It's
as if Frederick Hayek had been exhumed for the occasion.
POSTSCRIPT:
Those
who follow the behaviour of financial institutions and the workings of
Neoliberalism will find very little that is new in the above.
Claims
that tax cuts will benefit the community at large when in fact they will
benefit only some of the super-rich are simply more of the same. There are many
articles and books about Neoliberal economics. Last year, as those who follow
George Monbiot will already be aware, Monbiot’s “How Did We Get into
This Mess?”
was published by Verso in April 2015. He summarised his book in The Guardian
April 2015. Monbiot had an
earlier article on the same theme in early 2013.
___________
The following, an
extract from Monbiot’s summary of his book, is key economic history:
But in the 1970s,
when Keynesian policies began to fall apart and economic crises struck on both
sides of the Atlantic, neoliberal ideas began to enter the mainstream. As
Friedman remarked, “when the time came that you had to change … there was an
alternative ready there to be picked up”. With the help of sympathetic
journalists and political advisers, elements of neoliberalism, especially its
prescriptions for monetary policy, were adopted by Jimmy Carter’s
administration in the US and Jim Callaghan’s government in Britain.
After Margaret
Thatcher and Ronald Reagan took power, the rest of the package soon followed:
massive tax cuts for the rich, the crushing of trade unions, deregulation,
privatisation, outsourcing and competition in public services. Through the IMF,
the World Bank, the Maastricht treaty and the World Trade Organisation,
neoliberal policies were imposed – often without democratic consent – on much
of the world. Most remarkable was its adoption among parties that once belonged
to the left: Labour and the Democrats, for example. As Stedman Jones notes, “it
is hard to think of another utopia to have been as fully realised.”
It may seem strange
that a doctrine promising choice and freedom should have been promoted with the
slogan “there is no alternative”. But, as Hayek remarked on a visit to
Pinochet’s Chile – one of the first nations in which the programme was
comprehensively applied – “my personal preference leans toward a liberal dictatorship
rather than toward a democratic government devoid of liberalism”. The freedom
that neoliberalism offers, which sounds so beguiling when expressed in general
terms, turns out to mean freedom for the pike, not for the minnows.
Numerous articles
have appeared since 2008 about the Global Financial Crisis, not least by
Michael Lewis: his book The Big Short
was made into a film. The film Margin
Call deals with the same themes. Both films are extremely high quality!
Many ask why none
of the executives of the banks which benefitted from huge bailouts by
government using taxpayer funds have ever gone to gaol.
____________
Goldman
Sachs director Greg Smith resigned in March 2012 after publishing an open letter in the
New York Times
accusing senior staff of being morally bankrupt and bent on extracting maximum
fees from clients by offloading unsuitable investment products.
Matt
Taibbi at Rolling Stone has been
particularly active in covering this and the way government officials all the
way to the US Attorney-General Eric Holder have managed to have next to nothing
done about it all. Taibbi’s stories show, amongst other things how the SEC
(Securities and Exchange Commission) “covered up Wall Street crimes” destroying
records and whitewashing files (August 17 2011), how the biggest banks took
part in a nationwide bid-rigging conspiracy until caught on tape (June 21 2012)
and how HSBC “hooked up with drug traffickers and terrorists and got away with
it” (February 14 2013) and much more.
No comments:
Post a Comment